Published on 6 April 2023
Authors : Clémence Berson, Elisa Busson

Post n°313. Job-to-job moves usually enable employees to improve their pay or working conditions. It is therefore an important factor in wage dynamics. Resignations, which often indicate a job change, can be used to forecast wage and inflation trends.

Image Changes in resignation and job-to-job rates in France
Chart 1: Changes in resignation and job-to-job rates in France
Source: Dares, Insee, authors' calculations.

Note: Resignations (establishments with more than 10 employees) = quarterly data; job changes = annual data (Berson et al. 2020); shaded periods = negative change in real GDP.

Wages and job-to-job moves

The negative empirical relationship between nominal wage changes and the unemployment rate is known as the Phillips curve. A fall in unemployment raises employees’ bargaining power, which pushes up wages, and vice versa.

For some time now, this correlation has been the subject of debate. Between the early 1970s and the mid-1990s, the coefficient of the relationship has decreased. This is referred to as the flattening of the Phillips curve. It has since remained stable, leading to a relatively flat curve (Rue de la banque No. 56, February 2018).  According to Moscarini and Postel-Vinay (2016), the Phillips curve has even disappeared in the United States. Conversely, these authors highlight a strong correlation between wage evolution on the one hand and the rate of resignations and job changes on the other. Indeed, individuals generally leave their previous job if they are offered a higher wage or better working conditions. Thus, job-to-job flows lead to a rise in the nominal wages of employees who change jobs. These same flows can also have an impact on the wages of individuals who do not change jobs: employers will tend to raise the wages of their employees to encourage them to stay with their company.

As job-to-job moves are usually only identifiable with a time lag, i.e. the time it takes to compile the data, they can be approximated by the resignation rate in the economy. This rate can be viewed as an indicator of nominal wage growth (see Faberman and Justiniano, 2015 for the United States). Indeed, individuals who change jobs usually resign from their previous job and go directly to a new one, without being unemployed or exiting the labour market.

In France, wages are correlated with resignations

This relationship between job changes and wage dynamics is also observed in France.

If the analysis is restricted to persons with a job for more than one year, the wages of persons changing jobs are generally higher than those of people staying in the same job. Berson et al. (2020) show that job-to-job flows are strongly linked to wage dynamics: all other things being equal, over the period 1995-2015, French employees who changed jobs earned on average 1.8 percentage points more than if they had not changed jobs. However, the wage evolution remains correlated with the departmental unemployment rate through the wages of job changers, as a one percentage point increase in the unemployment rate reduces the wage gain of job switching by 0.23 percentage points. The smaller response of wages to job switching and the significant impact of the unemployment rate in France compared to the United States (see Hahn et al. 2021) are mainly due to the fact that job changes are less frequent in France, due to structural differences between the two economies and a more rigid labour market.

Resignation rates and wage dynamics are also correlated in France. Chart 1 shows the co-movement of job-to-job moves and resignations, with a rise in resignations and job changes during periods of economic growth, and a decline during periods of stagnation or recession, shown by the shaded areas. Both series are indeed cyclical: individuals are more likely to change jobs when economic conditions are favourable and more job opportunities are available. Companies are also more likely to offer higher wages to attract candidates. These higher wages provide an incentive for individuals to change jobs. During a recession, the opposite effect can be observed: there are fewer job offers, individuals have a lower bargaining power and resign less. Indeed, in France, resignations peak during periods of economic recovery.

Image Resignation rates and changes in wage indicators in France
Chart 2: Resignation rates and changes in wage indicators in France
Source: Dares, Insee.

Note: Quarterly data; resignations and basic monthly wages concern establishments with more than 10 employees; year-on-year changes

Chart 2.A and Table 1 show a correlation of about 49% between the share of resignations in total employment and the year-on-year change in the basic monthly wage (BMW). The BMW includes neither bonuses (except, where applicable, the bonus linked to the reduction in working hours) nor overtime. It is a gross wage, before deduction of social security contributions and before payment of social benefits. The correlation is strongest when one uses the resignation rate, lagged by one year relative to the BMW (70%). This correlation coefficient is close to but slightly lower than that observed in the United States (78%). The correlation with the average wage per capita (AWC) is even stronger when the two indicators are contemporaneous. The AWC is derived from national accounts and is the ratio of the gross wage bill paid by all employers over the number of employees in natural persons. The share of resignations in total employment and the labour cost index, i.e., the average cost of an employee for a company, are also correlated (67%), but this correlation has tended to decrease over time (Chart 3 and Table 1).

Image Changes in the resignation rate and unit labour costs in France
Chart 3: Changes in the resignation rate and unit labour costs in France
Note: Quarterly data; resignations concern establishments with more than 10 employees; year-on-year changes.Source: Dares and Insee, authors' calculations.

Note: Quarterly data; resignations concern establishments with more than 10 employees; year-on-year changes.

These links between the resignation rate on the one hand, and the basic wage and the cost of labour on the other, lead us to consider the relationship between resignations and inflation. As the cost of labour is part of a company’s production costs, a rise in production costs may be passed on to prices and have an impact on the inflation rate. Furthermore, individuals consume according to their income: if their income increases, their demand for goods and services also increases, which may generate inflation. Thus, the resignation rate in the economy could be correlated with inflation and could be a leading indicator of inflation.

Correlation between inflation and resignations

We look at the relationship between the resignation rate and core inflation, i.e., inflation excluding variations in the most volatile prices of energy and food (Chart 4).

The correlation between the share of resignations in total employment and core inflation reaches its maximum when the resignation indicator is lagged by four quarters (at 73% on French data). This statistical test indicates that the share of resignations in past quarters can help forecast inflation trends.

Image Changes in the resignation rate and inflation in France
Chart 4: Changes in the resignation rate and inflation in France
Source: Dares, Eurostat

 Note: resignations concern establishments with more than 10 employees; year-on-year changes.

Faberman and Justiniano (2015) show that in the United States there is a 94% correlation between the resignation rate and wage trends (labour cost index) two quarters later and 53% with the gap between actual and long-run inflation. This suggests that changes in the share of resignations in total employment lead to changes in wage and inflation trends six months to a year later.

In France, the results are less clear-cut but there is also a Granger causality which indicates that the resignation rate can help forecast wage trends and hence inflation. However, the reverse is not observed: wage trends do not help forecast the resignation rate.

Image Correlation between the resignation rate, wage trends and the inflation gap
Table 1: Correlation between the resignation rate, wage trends and the inflation gap
Source: Authors' calculations based on Dares, Insee and Eurostat data.

Note: Period from Q4 1999 to Q4 2019; year-on-year changes.